Matches in SemOpenAlex for { <https://semopenalex.org/work/W100871208> ?p ?o ?g. }
Showing items 1 to 90 of
90
with 100 items per page.
- W100871208 endingPage "27" @default.
- W100871208 startingPage "1" @default.
- W100871208 abstract "The industrial revolution and the subsequent industrialization of the economies occurred first in temperate regions. We argue that this and the associated positive correlation between absolute latitude and GDP per capita are due to the fact that countries located far from the equator suffered more profound seasonal fluctuations in climate, namely stronger and longer winters. We propose a growth model of biased innovations that accounts for these facts and show that countries located in temperate regions were more likely to create or adopt capital-intensive modes of production.The intuition behind this result is that savings are used to smooth consumption; therefore, in places where output fluctuations are more profound, savings are bigger. Because the incentives to innovate depend on the relative supply factors, economies where savings are bigger are more likely to create or adopt capital-intensive technologies.Keywords: Absolute Latitude, Seasons, Endogenous Growth, Capital Using InnovationsJEL classification: N00, O00, O11, O31, O33(ProQuest: ... denotes formulae omitted.)1. INTRODUCTIONThe industrial revolution occurred first in temperate regions and, since then, the world has experienced a massive absolute divergence in the distribution of incomes across countries. Indeed, today there is a positive correlation between absolute latitude and GDP per capita. Moreover, only three tropical economies (Hong Kong, Singapore, and Taiwan) are classified as high-income by the World Bank, while all countries within regions zoned as temperate had either middle or high-income economies.We argue that climatic conditions affect incentives to save in primitive economies in such a way that economies located in temperate regions are more likely to become capital abundant. In primitive economies the main source of output fluctuations is climatic and these are bigger in places located far away from the equator. Indeed, both the harvest per year and the diversification of crops are higher in tropical countries (see Chang, 1997). During the frost days in winter there is no harvest, transportation is difficult, people need more energy and, in general, surviving demands much more work. The response of people to these natural forces is saving during the good days to make bad days better. The stronger the winter the higher the level of savings needed to survive during the frost days. Finally, economies where the savings are systematically bigger are more likely to both, create and adopt capital intensive technologies. Once an economy begins to use capital intensive technologies a process of capital accumulation and capital improvement starts. Capital abundance generates the incentives for capital-using innovations and capital-using technologies generate the incentives for capital accumulation.Many endogenous growth models predict poverty traps, that is, depending on the initial abundance of capital economies can present long run growth or be trapped in a steady state with no economic growth.1 In particular, according to the literature of biased technological change the incentives to innovate depend on the relative supply of factors: in capital abundant economies individuals have incentives to make capital-using innovations while in economies where capital is scarce there are no incentives for this type of innovation.2 These innovations increase the elasticity of output with respect to capital as well as the incentives to save, so a virtuous circle derives capital abundant economies to long-run growth. Models of factor saving innovations generally predict that both the elasticity of output with respect to capital and the capital income share must be higher in richer economies. However, in general these models do not try to explain differences in initial conditions. Among these lines, Peretto and Seater (2006) present a model where the saving rate is exogenous and prove that differences in this variable can explain long run income differences. …" @default.
- W100871208 created "2016-06-24" @default.
- W100871208 creator A5012806521 @default.
- W100871208 date "2012-12-01" @default.
- W100871208 modified "2023-10-16" @default.
- W100871208 title "SEASONAL FLUCTUATIONS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH" @default.
- W100871208 cites W1487455743 @default.
- W100871208 cites W1511129506 @default.
- W100871208 cites W1523587548 @default.
- W100871208 cites W1534909329 @default.
- W100871208 cites W1544556248 @default.
- W100871208 cites W1568110160 @default.
- W100871208 cites W1607114424 @default.
- W100871208 cites W1704056767 @default.
- W100871208 cites W1954131431 @default.
- W100871208 cites W1974723286 @default.
- W100871208 cites W1981935076 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2006558343 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2012774161 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2031919903 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2062616771 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2108780127 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2109489467 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2110740819 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2111764760 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2121241047 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2129750907 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2134016729 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2164141257 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2169030761 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2170105205 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2170222801 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2175690459 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2318870795 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2326599995 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2742438606 @default.
- W100871208 cites W2800185043 @default.
- W100871208 cites W3021022626 @default.
- W100871208 cites W3021593216 @default.
- W100871208 cites W3022227647 @default.
- W100871208 cites W3121565390 @default.
- W100871208 cites W3121586043 @default.
- W100871208 cites W3121762824 @default.
- W100871208 cites W3122157058 @default.
- W100871208 cites W3122226698 @default.
- W100871208 cites W3122313894 @default.
- W100871208 cites W3122422405 @default.
- W100871208 cites W3122705141 @default.
- W100871208 cites W3124131699 @default.
- W100871208 cites W3124344332 @default.
- W100871208 cites W3124488712 @default.
- W100871208 cites W3125996676 @default.
- W100871208 cites W3193006831 @default.
- W100871208 doi "https://doi.org/10.35866/caujed.2012.37.4.001" @default.
- W100871208 hasPublicationYear "2012" @default.
- W100871208 type Work @default.
- W100871208 sameAs 100871208 @default.
- W100871208 citedByCount "8" @default.
- W100871208 countsByYear W1008712082015 @default.
- W100871208 countsByYear W1008712082016 @default.
- W100871208 countsByYear W1008712082018 @default.
- W100871208 countsByYear W1008712082019 @default.
- W100871208 countsByYear W1008712082021 @default.
- W100871208 crossrefType "journal-article" @default.
- W100871208 hasAuthorship W100871208A5012806521 @default.
- W100871208 hasConcept C149782125 @default.
- W100871208 hasConcept C162324750 @default.
- W100871208 hasConceptScore W100871208C149782125 @default.
- W100871208 hasConceptScore W100871208C162324750 @default.
- W100871208 hasIssue "4" @default.
- W100871208 hasLocation W1008712081 @default.
- W100871208 hasOpenAccess W100871208 @default.
- W100871208 hasPrimaryLocation W1008712081 @default.
- W100871208 hasRelatedWork W1522504334 @default.
- W100871208 hasRelatedWork W1973538245 @default.
- W100871208 hasRelatedWork W2023446719 @default.
- W100871208 hasRelatedWork W2030617584 @default.
- W100871208 hasRelatedWork W2056210026 @default.
- W100871208 hasRelatedWork W2142249680 @default.
- W100871208 hasRelatedWork W2161519270 @default.
- W100871208 hasRelatedWork W3149328373 @default.
- W100871208 hasRelatedWork W331667891 @default.
- W100871208 hasRelatedWork W2142213187 @default.
- W100871208 hasVolume "37" @default.
- W100871208 isParatext "false" @default.
- W100871208 isRetracted "false" @default.
- W100871208 magId "100871208" @default.
- W100871208 workType "article" @default.