Matches in SemOpenAlex for { <https://semopenalex.org/work/W139179091> ?p ?o ?g. }
Showing items 1 to 76 of
76
with 100 items per page.
- W139179091 startingPage "427" @default.
- W139179091 abstract "During the past two decades there has been a heated debate about the causes of the German so-called Wirtschaftswunder (economic miracle) after the Second World War. This debate came somewhat unexpectedly, as the German war generation always took it for granted that the impressive growth record the 1950s and 60s was a consequence of economic liberalization after 15 years of tight planning and state interventionism under the Nazi dictatorship (Buchheim 1989). (1) Indeed, after the introduction of the Soziale Marktwirtschaft (social market economy) 1948, Ludwig Erhard, the first federal economics minister, enjoyed a legendary reputation. Nevertheless, Erhard never saw himself as a miracle man. He always emphasized that Germany's rapid growth was due to a sound economic policy, particular the implementation of a free economic system (Erhard 1958). (2) In the 1980s, this view was challenged by historians and economists who argued that Germany's postwar growth was essentially the result of a reconstruction boom after the lost war. The main German advocate of this reconstruction theory was the historian Werner Abelshauser (1983). He questioned the impact of the currency reform--a core ingredient of Erhard's economic policy--on economic growth. Rudi Dornbusch also questioned the conventional view. He pointed to the Japanese experience achieving strong economic growth the 1950s and 60s in an environment where competition and were decidedly absent, and argued that France performed nearly as well as Germany a system far away from German liberalism (Dornbusch 1993: 882). Dornbusch is wrong for two reasons. First, Japanese growth was highest the 1960s, not the 50s when the income gap was largest. Second, France's growth rates did not approach those Germany, which were much higher. Solving the Controversy Crude theories linking exceptional growth to war devastations were originally formulated as early as the 19th century. In 1848, John Stuart Mill (1848: 93) wrote: An enemy lays waste a country by fire and sword, and destroys and carries away nearly all the movable wealth existing it; all the inhabitants are mined, and yet, a few years after, everything is much as it was before. More than 100 years later, K.C. Kogiku (1966: 154) explained Japan's high postwar growth terms of Friedman's Law: Destroy the greater part of a nation's fixed capital war activity and dislocate the whole economic structure. Eventual recovery from this chaotic state of affairs will be rapid, giving a growth rate of 8-10 per cent annually. This is indeed the rate of growth Germany experienced the early postwar period. (3) Turning to formal growth theory, reconstruction booms can be easily explained with the standard neoclassical model originally proposed by Solow (1956, 1957). Assuming Harrod-neutral technical progress, the long-run growth rate of an economy is determined by its population growth rate and the rate of technological progress. Per capita income grows at the latter rate. Using this framework, a temporary destruction of a country's physical capital stock causes an immediate decline the the capital-labor ratio to a point well below its long-run equilibrium level. This increased capital scarcity increases the productivity of capital and leads to higher productivity growth rates. Consequently, per capita income rises at above equilibrium growth rates and asymptotically approaches the long-run growth path. The growth rate itself is inversely related to the difference between the actual and the equilibrium capital-labor ratio. At the beginning of the reconstruction phase, growth rates are highest but gradually decline as the economy moves to its long-run growth path. Based on this theory, there have been a great number of empirical studies, particularly a cross-section context. The standard growth equation of these studies relates income growth to initial per capita income and several other determinants, including population growth, trade orientation, and investment rates physical and human capital (Barro 1995). …" @default.
- W139179091 created "2016-06-24" @default.
- W139179091 creator A5061890894 @default.
- W139179091 date "2002-01-01" @default.
- W139179091 modified "2023-09-23" @default.
- W139179091 title "Germany's Postwar Growth: Economic Miracle or Reconstruction Boom?" @default.
- W139179091 cites W1488346327 @default.
- W139179091 cites W1490983209 @default.
- W139179091 cites W1497679885 @default.
- W139179091 cites W1546363427 @default.
- W139179091 cites W1602104331 @default.
- W139179091 cites W2038683866 @default.
- W139179091 cites W2046236093 @default.
- W139179091 cites W2070631858 @default.
- W139179091 cites W2092081162 @default.
- W139179091 cites W2170216214 @default.
- W139179091 cites W250703710 @default.
- W139179091 cites W2624561140 @default.
- W139179091 cites W3122032365 @default.
- W139179091 cites W631251289 @default.
- W139179091 hasPublicationYear "2002" @default.
- W139179091 type Work @default.
- W139179091 sameAs 139179091 @default.
- W139179091 citedByCount "3" @default.
- W139179091 crossrefType "journal-article" @default.
- W139179091 hasAuthorship W139179091A5061890894 @default.
- W139179091 hasConcept C136264566 @default.
- W139179091 hasConcept C137355542 @default.
- W139179091 hasConcept C162324750 @default.
- W139179091 hasConcept C165556158 @default.
- W139179091 hasConcept C17744445 @default.
- W139179091 hasConcept C199539241 @default.
- W139179091 hasConcept C2778763365 @default.
- W139179091 hasConcept C2778875440 @default.
- W139179091 hasConcept C6303427 @default.
- W139179091 hasConcept C94625758 @default.
- W139179091 hasConceptScore W139179091C136264566 @default.
- W139179091 hasConceptScore W139179091C137355542 @default.
- W139179091 hasConceptScore W139179091C162324750 @default.
- W139179091 hasConceptScore W139179091C165556158 @default.
- W139179091 hasConceptScore W139179091C17744445 @default.
- W139179091 hasConceptScore W139179091C199539241 @default.
- W139179091 hasConceptScore W139179091C2778763365 @default.
- W139179091 hasConceptScore W139179091C2778875440 @default.
- W139179091 hasConceptScore W139179091C6303427 @default.
- W139179091 hasConceptScore W139179091C94625758 @default.
- W139179091 hasIssue "3" @default.
- W139179091 hasLocation W1391790911 @default.
- W139179091 hasOpenAccess W139179091 @default.
- W139179091 hasPrimaryLocation W1391790911 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W1539061666 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W1993043751 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W2015277991 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W2015684143 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W2100236835 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W2123662801 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W2126864504 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W2145517084 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W2182818368 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W2460189814 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W2463792515 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W2466977144 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W2476508651 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W2476625049 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W2482332794 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W2485732007 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W2486040642 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W2488222035 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W2489267034 @default.
- W139179091 hasRelatedWork W3121358539 @default.
- W139179091 hasVolume "21" @default.
- W139179091 isParatext "false" @default.
- W139179091 isRetracted "false" @default.
- W139179091 magId "139179091" @default.
- W139179091 workType "article" @default.