Matches in SemOpenAlex for { <https://semopenalex.org/work/W1964368889> ?p ?o ?g. }
Showing items 1 to 73 of
73
with 100 items per page.
- W1964368889 endingPage "121" @default.
- W1964368889 startingPage "106" @default.
- W1964368889 abstract "Introduction The governments in the Middle East have always tended to treat the Bedouin as second rate citizens. Even today many government spokesmen argue that the Bedouin contribute little to the region's national economies, that they live apart from the settled population and produce only for their own subsistence (see, for instance, the articles in Arab League 1965 (1); Abou Zeid 1996). The Bedouin's nomadic way of life is viewed as little more than an attempt to opt out of civil obligations, such as military service and payment of taxes. By settling the Bedouin, governments hoped to make them more productive and more governable. As they were thought to practise a subsistence economy (see, for instance, Cole 1975: 145), the economic dislocation and loss of production caused by settlement was often ignored. On the contrary, the officials believed that as settled peasants the Bedouin would at last enter the market economy. The preconceptions of the government officials as to the nature of the nomads affected their settlement policies: they tended to concentrate on housing groups in permanent villages and on converting them to agriculture. During the nineteenth century governments made numerous attempts to forcibly settle Bedouin. For a while these projects seemed to work, but as soon as the authorities averted their watchful gaze, the Bedouin resumed their pastoral way of life (Sachau 1883: 264). This should have been self-evident, for animal husbandry requires larger inputs of labour and capital than farming, and generally yields higher incomes (Abu-Rabia 1994: 107-127). King Ibn Sa'ud clearly knew this, when he settled his Bedouin militias (ikhwan) in agricultural colonies from 1912 onward. He intentionally deprived the men of their pastoral resources in order to make them dependent and pliant. They were meant to rely on regular subventions paid by the state in return for military services (Kostiner 1991: 230-32). By the 1960s most of the inhabitants of these settlements had returned to a pastoral way of life (Cole 1975: 124). A more effective, and no less harmful, policy was applied in Syria and Iraq; it allowed chiefs to acquire large tracts of tribal pasture and convert them to agriculture. This left the poorer members of the tribe little choice but to become sharecroppers of their chiefs, while wealthier ones continued their profitable pastoral activities (Stein 1967: 105-108; Abujaber 1989: 177-196). The oil-rich post Second World War Gulf states did not need to engage in forcible sedentarisation. A different economic constellation had transformed the issue of Bedouin control. Most Bedouin men sought work in the oil industry, which offered higher rewards than animal husbandry. Their families back in the tribal territories maintained a permanent home base, to which the men returned during leaves. The women and children remained `at home' and continued to raise animals as a hedge against unemployment and other expected mishaps. While the income from wage labour was good, animals were not put up for sale (Asche 1981: 138). But if the men lost their jobs, they would return home, revive the alternative economy and make a living out of it (this has been shown for South Sinai; see Marx 1987). Most tribesman were enrolled in the National Guard, and thus received another salary. Periodically they were called up for short training periods and were thus at the beck and call of the authorities. In the sparsely populated countries of the Gulf, land became valuable only when particular resources, such as oil wells, urban infrastructures and services, were attached to it. Therefore the State could impound large areas, at little cost to itself, and mm them into military installations, oilfields or tourist sites, such as nature reserves (see Chatty, in this issue). In the absence of a local infrastructure of capital, knowledge and skills, foreign investors and tourists were expected to make a large and rapid contribution to the economy. …" @default.
- W1964368889 created "2016-06-24" @default.
- W1964368889 creator A5030643140 @default.
- W1964368889 date "2000-12-01" @default.
- W1964368889 modified "2023-10-03" @default.
- W1964368889 title "Land and Work: Negev Bedouin Struggle with Israeli Bureaucracies" @default.
- W1964368889 cites W150225213 @default.
- W1964368889 cites W1617173939 @default.
- W1964368889 cites W1974472125 @default.
- W1964368889 cites W2017467392 @default.
- W1964368889 cites W2026777274 @default.
- W1964368889 cites W2494930665 @default.
- W1964368889 cites W412359547 @default.
- W1964368889 cites W609546105 @default.
- W1964368889 doi "https://doi.org/10.3167/082279400782310575" @default.
- W1964368889 hasPublicationYear "2000" @default.
- W1964368889 type Work @default.
- W1964368889 sameAs 1964368889 @default.
- W1964368889 citedByCount "31" @default.
- W1964368889 countsByYear W19643688892012 @default.
- W1964368889 countsByYear W19643688892013 @default.
- W1964368889 countsByYear W19643688892014 @default.
- W1964368889 countsByYear W19643688892016 @default.
- W1964368889 countsByYear W19643688892020 @default.
- W1964368889 crossrefType "journal-article" @default.
- W1964368889 hasAuthorship W1964368889A5030643140 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConcept C127413603 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConcept C166957645 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConcept C17744445 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConcept C18762648 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConcept C199539241 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConcept C205649164 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConcept C2549261 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConcept C51575053 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConcept C526734887 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConcept C78519656 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConcept C91375879 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConcept C94625758 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConcept C95457728 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConceptScore W1964368889C127413603 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConceptScore W1964368889C166957645 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConceptScore W1964368889C17744445 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConceptScore W1964368889C18762648 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConceptScore W1964368889C199539241 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConceptScore W1964368889C205649164 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConceptScore W1964368889C2549261 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConceptScore W1964368889C51575053 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConceptScore W1964368889C526734887 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConceptScore W1964368889C78519656 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConceptScore W1964368889C91375879 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConceptScore W1964368889C94625758 @default.
- W1964368889 hasConceptScore W1964368889C95457728 @default.
- W1964368889 hasIssue "2" @default.
- W1964368889 hasLocation W19643688891 @default.
- W1964368889 hasOpenAccess W1964368889 @default.
- W1964368889 hasPrimaryLocation W19643688891 @default.
- W1964368889 hasRelatedWork W1583500635 @default.
- W1964368889 hasRelatedWork W1992609303 @default.
- W1964368889 hasRelatedWork W2038985689 @default.
- W1964368889 hasRelatedWork W2049867576 @default.
- W1964368889 hasRelatedWork W2327400576 @default.
- W1964368889 hasRelatedWork W2748952813 @default.
- W1964368889 hasRelatedWork W2899084033 @default.
- W1964368889 hasRelatedWork W3033565456 @default.
- W1964368889 hasRelatedWork W3070811913 @default.
- W1964368889 hasRelatedWork W271343173 @default.
- W1964368889 hasVolume "4" @default.
- W1964368889 isParatext "false" @default.
- W1964368889 isRetracted "false" @default.
- W1964368889 magId "1964368889" @default.
- W1964368889 workType "article" @default.