Matches in SemOpenAlex for { <https://semopenalex.org/work/W2107420527> ?p ?o ?g. }
Showing items 1 to 89 of
89
with 100 items per page.
- W2107420527 abstract "Despite two decades of the Common Fishery Policy (CFP), the fishery politics of the European Union (EU) is considered a failure when it comes to securing fish-stocks. This paper explores reasons to this state of affairs by analysing the views and opinions among those subjected to regulations, namely professional fishermen (in Sweden). Since the capacity of any natural management regime to protect the resources depends on appropriators’ compliance, the prospects of sustainable natural management depends on improved understanding of when and why appropriators consent, and ultimately comply, with a regulative policy. So, when do fishermen comply with a fishery management regime? Instrumental views give a straightforward explanation; when the risk of being caught is considered high (and the potential economic profit of rule-breaking is low). More normative views point at various “qualities of government” such as procedural fairness, distributive justice, trust and legitimacy, but is much less specified in terms of actual explanations to appropriators’ actions. This paper adds a piece to the compliance puzzle by, relying on the model presented by Levi(1997), exploring the importance of 1) imbalanced burdens and 2) trust in authorities. Results confirm the importance of trust in authorities but contradict the idea that experiences of imbalance in burdens have a negative effect on legitimacy. Strikingly enough, fishermen who believe that other governments take greater concern in their fishing-fleets than the Swedish government, value the principles of Swedish fishery politics more. Daniel Berlin Ulrika Moller Department of Political Science, Department of Political Science, Goteborg University Goteborg University Box 711 Box 711 SE 405 30 Goteborg, Sweden SE 405 30 Goteborg, Sweden daniel.berlin@pol.gu.se ulrika.moller@pol.gu.se Sverker C. Jagers Department of Political Science, Goteborg University Box 711 SE 405 30 Goteborg, Sweden sverker.jagers@pol.gu.se Why Accept State Regulations? What make us accept and comply with regulations we are subjected to by the state? According to the instrumental approaches launched in the economic literature, it is mostly a matter of the sanctions that might follow if we chose not to. According to more normative approaches launched in political science and sociology this has also to do with a number of assessments we make concerning the process and outcome of policy: procedural fairness, distributive justice, trust and legitimacy. An implication of the normative approach is that with diverseness in implementation and exercise of policy, comes the risk of undermined legitimacy and a lower degree of compliance as a consequence. European fishery policy bears characteristics of diverseness in the sense that member-states may be more or less ambitious in implementing the Common Fishery Politics (CFP). According to the normative approach we should therefore expect the fishermen of EU member states to – once they have discovered the imbalances in burdens between fishermen of different nationalities – be less inclined both to trust the regime and to consider it as legitimate. The empirical findings presented in this paper, however, partly contradict these expectations. European Fishery: A Common Policy with Imbalanced Burdens Fish, as a global common, creates collective action problems on at least two levels. First, the short-term interest of each single fishing crew to maximize their catch runs contrary to the long term collective good of sustainable fishery and preserved fish-stocks. Second, while the collectively preferable strategy for all states would be to impose consistent regulations and supervision, each state has a short term interest to provide relatively soft conditions for their own fleet. The standard solution to escape these kinds of collective action problems is various forms of cooperation, such as setting up common rules and sanctions to prevent freeriding.1 If one considers the general cooperative structure of the European Union (EU) and the issue-specific cooperation in the Common Fishery Politics (CFP), one might therefore expect that over-exploitation is a minor problem in European fishing-waters. Especially since the CFP has been running for two decades – long enough to develop efficient supra-national institutional arrangements to reduce incentives for states and fishing-crews to free-ride. However, this is clearly not the case. The fishery politics of the European Union is severely criticized and judged a failure by several crucial actors such as the European Court of Auditors.2 One important shortcoming revealed by a study carried out by the EU Commission indicates that there is a high degree of misreporting of catches. Inspections in the Baltic Sea 2005/2006 show that 1 The risk of over-exploitation and degradation of common pool resources (CPR), such as fish stocks, has of course most famously been captured in Garrett Hardin’s metaphor “The Tragedy of the Commons” where “freedom in the commons brings ruin to all” (Hardin 1968:1244). 2 The European Court of Auditors. Sarskild rapport nr 7/2007. inspected vessels quite systematically report larger catches than non-inspected vessels.3 For Latvian vessels, the discrepancy was 8 percent, for Swedish vessels it was 21 percent, and for Polish vessels 48 percent. Assumingly, plain cheating is a core (although not necessarily the only) cause for this discrepancy in landings. Another highlighted incongruity in the CFP is that it involves imbalances of the burdens imposed on fishermen. Such disproportions are potentially risky since they are assumed to negatively impact the legitimacy of the regime as well as the trust in authoritiesat least among the offended groups.4 The theoretical foundations of this argument are further elaborated later in this paper, but it should be noted already at this stage that it is not the objective distribution of burdens that is in focus. Rather, the core of the matter is how fishermen perceive the balance and imbalance of burdens. The purpose of this paper is to test whether Swedish fishermen’s perceptions of their relative burdens within the CFP impact their trust in the national fishery authorities (Swedish Board of Fisheries, SBF) and the degree to which they consider the regulations legitimate. Judging from earlier research and official reports, there are at least two sources of perceived imbalance in burdens. Burden as governmental concern. The Common Fishery Policy (CFP) of the European Union involves a resource management element. The resource management aims at recovering and preserving the resource stocks through regulations such as catch limits, quotas, protected areas, restricted access zones, effort limits and gear restrictions. The shape and content of these regulations are the result of national governments negotiating with each other. Swedish fishermen have perceptions of in which degree the Swedish government takes the interests of the fishing industry into consideration in these negotiations. They evaluate how concerned their government is compared to how concerned other governments are for their fishing fleets. The positions and strategies of a government depend on a number of factors such as the relative importance of fisheries, the size of the fishing fleet and the strength of the fishery lobby.5 The principle of relative stability set frames for the distributions of fishing rights and quotas among the member countries. Still, the bargaining about the TAC levels as such can, in the minds of fishermen, indicate whether their government shows low or high concern for the fishing industry. Ever since the first days of the CFP, there have been substantial differences between countries when it comes to formulating the CFP and decides on regulations. In a study on the negotiations of the 2003 CFP reform, two main 3 “Evaluation report in catch registration in Baltic-sea member states” (January, 2007). 4 European Court of Auditors. Sarskild rapport 7/2007 5 Lequesne 2004, SLI 2006, Hasselberg 1997." @default.
- W2107420527 created "2016-06-24" @default.
- W2107420527 creator A5000922861 @default.
- W2107420527 creator A5005866417 @default.
- W2107420527 creator A5035713595 @default.
- W2107420527 date "2008-04-01" @default.
- W2107420527 modified "2023-09-26" @default.
- W2107420527 title "Navigating Towards Effective Fishery Management: Exploring the Impact of Imbalanced Burdens on Regime Legitimacy" @default.
- W2107420527 cites W1502254273 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W1527033286 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W1573084417 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W1606766006 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W1993840256 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W1997146242 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W1998515443 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W2028088874 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W2033588282 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W2034856494 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W2081958455 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W2082310287 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W2089109354 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W2137361401 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W2165702945 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W2175723801 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W2187315605 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W2753514269 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W3149953018 @default.
- W2107420527 cites W379602626 @default.
- W2107420527 hasPublicationYear "2008" @default.
- W2107420527 type Work @default.
- W2107420527 sameAs 2107420527 @default.
- W2107420527 citedByCount "0" @default.
- W2107420527 crossrefType "journal-article" @default.
- W2107420527 hasAuthorship W2107420527A5000922861 @default.
- W2107420527 hasAuthorship W2107420527A5005866417 @default.
- W2107420527 hasAuthorship W2107420527A5035713595 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConcept C107826830 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConcept C144133560 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConcept C162324750 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConcept C17744445 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConcept C199539241 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConcept C202041845 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConcept C205649164 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConcept C46295352 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConcept C505870484 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConcept C514101110 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConcept C86803240 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConcept C91375879 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConcept C94625758 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConceptScore W2107420527C107826830 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConceptScore W2107420527C144133560 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConceptScore W2107420527C162324750 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConceptScore W2107420527C17744445 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConceptScore W2107420527C199539241 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConceptScore W2107420527C202041845 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConceptScore W2107420527C205649164 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConceptScore W2107420527C46295352 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConceptScore W2107420527C505870484 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConceptScore W2107420527C514101110 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConceptScore W2107420527C86803240 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConceptScore W2107420527C91375879 @default.
- W2107420527 hasConceptScore W2107420527C94625758 @default.
- W2107420527 hasLocation W21074205271 @default.
- W2107420527 hasOpenAccess W2107420527 @default.
- W2107420527 hasPrimaryLocation W21074205271 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W1231030326 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W1964159858 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W1976828628 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W1997731274 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W2030542418 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W2044968327 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W2054024199 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W2063410838 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W2129681811 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W2188601730 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W2219779232 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W2296383319 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W2378412365 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W2389780987 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W2390611872 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W249041954 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W2503017040 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W2886390712 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W2972339753 @default.
- W2107420527 hasRelatedWork W64132873 @default.
- W2107420527 isParatext "false" @default.
- W2107420527 isRetracted "false" @default.
- W2107420527 magId "2107420527" @default.
- W2107420527 workType "article" @default.