Matches in SemOpenAlex for { <https://semopenalex.org/work/W2121876220> ?p ?o ?g. }
Showing items 1 to 60 of
60
with 100 items per page.
- W2121876220 endingPage "1190" @default.
- W2121876220 startingPage "1189" @default.
- W2121876220 abstract "Book Review Health AffairsVol. 27, No. 4: China And India: Reform Goes Global Baby Boomers: Hope For The Best Or Plan For The Worst?Leonard D. SchaefferPUBLISHED:July/August 2008Free Accesshttps://doi.org/10.1377/hlthaff.27.4.1189AboutSectionsView PDFPermissions ShareShare onFacebookTwitterLinked InRedditEmail ToolsAdd to favoritesDownload CitationsTrack CitationsPermissionsDownload Exhibits TOPICSCosts and spendingBaby boomersMedicareSocial SecurityPaymentPoliticsMedicare savings programsHealth care providers In The Long Baby Boom, Jeff Goldsmith challenges the growing consensus that the projected increases in spending for Medicare and Social Security threaten the economic future of the United States. His effort to debunk the “catastropharians”—Goldsmith’s term for those who warn that, left unchecked, the federal spending generated by baby-boom retirement will lead to an unsustainable budget deficit for future generations—begins with an insightful discussion of baby-boomers’ values, attitudes, and behavior. Goldsmith makes three observations about baby boomers that should inform policy change: they are interested in continuing to work, their confidence in government is limited, and they accept that Social Security and Medicare will provide limited postretirement support. Goldsmith further asserts that baby boomers will be able to self-finance a significant percentage of their social needs, thus reducing the shift to younger workers. In addition, he argues, the wealth amassed by the top quartile will fuel future economic growth.Goldsmith says past is not prologue. He understands that the heterogeneity of the boomer population is significant. He stratifies them into three groups: Set for Life; Might Be OK; and Struggling and Anxious. His vision is flexible policy that gives greater choice and control over public benefits. Rejecting the one-size-fits-all solutions of the past is a promising approach to ending the practice of giving social subsidies to those who do not need them. Goldsmith’s optimism springs largely from his assumptions about boomers’ wealth. His data, however, are at odds with other analyses. For instance, the Center for Retirement Research (CRR) found that even if households work to age sixty-five and annuitize all of their financial assets, including receipts from reverse mortgages, 44 percent would still be “at risk” of being unable to maintain their standard of living in retirement. 1 Also, baby boomers are not all building reserves for retirement. Instead, many spend all of their earnings and more, contributing to the negative savings rate and huge credit card debt among the working population. 2Like most policy experts, Goldsmith selects information that advances his thesis. When the issues are as complex as Social Security and Medicare, however, the policy community has a responsibility to reconcile different data and conclusions to shape effective policy for a heterogeneous population. Since nearly all baby boomers will need and use Medicare, any discussion of boomers’ financial health must include the potential impact of private health care spending. The CRR study found that when health care (out-of-pocket payments) was factored in, the percentage of “at risk” households climbed from 44 percent to 61 percent. 3 In addition, the CRR estimated that an individual and couple should have $102,000 and $206,000, respectively, earmarked for health care when they retire. Fidelity Investments estimates that a couple will need $225,000 in savings for medical costs when they retire. 4 Most “Set for Lifers” probably can absorb such costs, but many “Might Be OKs” will be caught by surprise when they join the “Struggling and Anxious” because of health care costs. Goldsmith also underestimates the problem of rising health care costs for the Medicare program. He too easily dismisses the concerns of the comptroller general, the Congressional Budget Office (CBO), the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services, the Medicare trustees, and the sixteen economist members of the Brookings-Heritage Fiscal Seminar. Despite the diversity in ideology and politics, there is remarkable consistency that the “enormous gap between projected federal spending and revenues” must be narrowed. 5 Moreover, most agree that the rate of cost growth per beneficiary, not the number of beneficiaries, is the chief concern. Goldsmith chastises catastropharians for making fiscal projections that are “absurd” because they are based on current ground rules (p. 10). However, many credible organizations vary their assumptions with respect to growth rates and still conclude that the fiscal outlook is grim. The CBO has even changed its methodology to assume that Medicare will not grow at historical rates but will, in fact, slow because employers, households, and insurance firms will change their behavior to avoid reducing consumption of nonhealth goods. 6 Goldsmith also suggests that baby boomers will be the “economic engine” (p. 155) that allows the country to grow its way out of its fiscal problems. Unfortunately, he may be promoting a myth that perpetuates inaction. According to the Brookings-Heritage seminar, “we cannot grow our way to a sustainable budget outlook” (nor can we tax our way out). 7 Goldsmith further minimizes the risks of excessive borrowing from foreign countries. Goldsmith’s perspective is not as far from the catastropharians’ as he claims. After all, Goldsmith’s contrarian, optimistic vision still requires a challenging set of policy changes to avoid the economic consequences of “autopilot” federal spending. 8 Catastropharians and Goldsmith both agree that the real problem is evading tough choices. And Goldsmith’s proposals are worth exploring. It makes sense to consider simplifying the Medicare benefit and to incorporate long-term care. In addition, one of Goldsmith’s best insights is that “Medicare has become an entitlement program for providers of health care” (pp. 33, 109). We must address that by changing incentives to health care providers through payment reform and eliminating up to 30 percent of unnecessary medical spending. Whether one is a catastropharian or an optimist, after one decides what needs to happen, the real problem is how to get it done. The politics of health care and Social Security have prevented meaningful change. Unless the health policy community acts quickly, those seeking a political decision to reduce the federal deficit or our dependence on foreign lenders may, by default, set future Social Security and Medicare policy. Goldsmith paints a persuasive picture of a more positive outcome for both baby boomers and our economy. I hope he is right.Leonard Schaeffer is chairman, Surgical Care Affiliates; senior advisor, TPG Capital; and the Judge Widney Professor at the University of Southern California. He is based in Santa Monica.The author gratefully acknowledges the review and comments of Dana E. McMurtry.NOTES1 A.H. Munnell et al., Health Care Costs Drive Up the National Retirement Risk Index, Issue Brief no. 8-3 (Boston: Center for Retirement Research at Boston College, February 2008 ), 1. Google Scholar 2 K. Chu , “Retirees Up against Debt,” USA Today, 23 January 2007 . Google Scholar 3 Munnell et al., Health Care Costs Drive Up the National Retirement Risk Index , 4 . Google Scholar 4 E.A. Powell , “Fidelity: Couple Needs $225,000 to Cover Health Care in Retirement,” AP Business Wire, 5 March 2008 . Google Scholar 5 J. Antos et al., “Taking Back Our Fiscal Future,” Brookings-Heritage Foundation Fiscal Seminar paper, April 2008 , p. 2. Google Scholar 6 Congressional Budget Office, The Long-Term Outlook for Health Care Spending (Washington: CBO, November 2007 ), 1. Google Scholar 7 Antos et al., “Taking Back,” 4–5. Google Scholar 8 Ibid., 8. Google Scholar Loading Comments... Please enable JavaScript to view the comments powered by Disqus. DetailsExhibitsReferencesRelated Article Metrics History Published online 1 July 2008 InformationCopyright 2008 by Project HOPE - The People-to-People Health Foundation, Inc.PDF download" @default.
- W2121876220 created "2016-06-24" @default.
- W2121876220 creator A5011016408 @default.
- W2121876220 date "2008-07-01" @default.
- W2121876220 modified "2023-10-16" @default.
- W2121876220 title "Baby Boomers: Hope For The Best Or Plan For The Worst?" @default.
- W2121876220 cites W1507972486 @default.
- W2121876220 cites W2341346074 @default.
- W2121876220 doi "https://doi.org/10.1377/hlthaff.27.4.1189" @default.
- W2121876220 hasPublicationYear "2008" @default.
- W2121876220 type Work @default.
- W2121876220 sameAs 2121876220 @default.
- W2121876220 citedByCount "0" @default.
- W2121876220 crossrefType "journal-article" @default.
- W2121876220 hasAuthorship W2121876220A5011016408 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConcept C15744967 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConcept C160735492 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConcept C162324750 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConcept C166957645 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConcept C2776505523 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConcept C2992755240 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConcept C3019122810 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConcept C4249254 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConcept C50522688 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConcept C71924100 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConcept C74909509 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConcept C95457728 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConceptScore W2121876220C15744967 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConceptScore W2121876220C160735492 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConceptScore W2121876220C162324750 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConceptScore W2121876220C166957645 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConceptScore W2121876220C2776505523 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConceptScore W2121876220C2992755240 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConceptScore W2121876220C3019122810 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConceptScore W2121876220C4249254 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConceptScore W2121876220C50522688 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConceptScore W2121876220C71924100 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConceptScore W2121876220C74909509 @default.
- W2121876220 hasConceptScore W2121876220C95457728 @default.
- W2121876220 hasIssue "4" @default.
- W2121876220 hasLocation W21218762201 @default.
- W2121876220 hasOpenAccess W2121876220 @default.
- W2121876220 hasPrimaryLocation W21218762201 @default.
- W2121876220 hasRelatedWork W1486402225 @default.
- W2121876220 hasRelatedWork W2413684465 @default.
- W2121876220 hasRelatedWork W2415185608 @default.
- W2121876220 hasRelatedWork W2469855333 @default.
- W2121876220 hasRelatedWork W2748952813 @default.
- W2121876220 hasRelatedWork W2802340790 @default.
- W2121876220 hasRelatedWork W2899084033 @default.
- W2121876220 hasRelatedWork W2994261825 @default.
- W2121876220 hasRelatedWork W4229898537 @default.
- W2121876220 hasRelatedWork W4379054332 @default.
- W2121876220 hasVolume "27" @default.
- W2121876220 isParatext "false" @default.
- W2121876220 isRetracted "false" @default.
- W2121876220 magId "2121876220" @default.
- W2121876220 workType "article" @default.