Matches in SemOpenAlex for { <https://semopenalex.org/work/W2140061355> ?p ?o ?g. }
- W2140061355 abstract "Abstract Individuals and societies have always adapted to change, whether catastrophic or slow onset. Over the last two centuries, however, governments have significantly extended their role as ultimate social manager of risk. It is as yet unclear whether, how, or to what extent governments will add adaptation to climate change to their portfolio of responsibilities. This report investigates this question on the basis of review and analysis of economic and policy thinking on the issues, and by using a new dataset on the 2011 Brisbane flood. Uncertainties about the future impacts of climate change obviate definitive conclusions about future adaptation actions and insights for specific situations cannot be generalised. Economic precepts suggest that governments should limit intervention to cases of genuine market failure, such as the provision of information on likely impacts of climate change including at the local level, or to support for people affected by uninsurable events. But any role as ‘insurer of last resort’ needs to be circumscribed by rigorous social cost-benefit analysis to ensure that government intervention is beneficial, in the context of the need to adapt to climatic changes. Although the phenomenon of ‘government failure’ is generally ignored in the adaptation literature (and often by policy makers), it too can stymie efficient adaptation. A standard justification for government intervention is market failure, including misperception of risk by individuals and businesses. We use Brisbane property prices before and after the January 2011 flood, as well as property-level flood risk information to test the hypothesis that buyers do not accurately perceive the risk of riverine flooding. The results indicate that buyers do take risk into account, and even discriminate between zones of differing flood risk. The concepts of ‘government as insurer of last resort’ and ‘government as insurer of first resort’ as alternative forms of intervention in markets are examined with a view to disambiguation. In contrast to much current thinking in academic and government circles, we conclude that the government should not act as an ‘adaptor of first or last resort’. Rather, government can best contribute to efficient adaptation by reducing the economic costs and institutional barriers to adaptation faced by individuals and organisations. Comprehensive micro-economic reform, and the promotion of institutional flexibility are potential ‘no regrets’ strategies because they will also promote economic growth and welfare. Please cite as: Dobes, L, Jotzo, F, Doupe, P 2013 Adaptor of last resort? An economic perspective on the Government’s role in adaptation to climate change, National Climate Change Adaptation Research Facility, Gold Coast, pp. 81. Individuals and societies have always adapted to change, whether catastrophic or slow onset. Over the last two centuries, however, governments have significantly extended their role as ultimate social manager of risk. It is as yet unclear whether, how, or to what extent governments will add adaptation to climate change to their portfolio of responsibilities. This report investigates this question on the basis of review and analysis of economic and policy thinking on the issues, and by using a new dataset on the 2011 Brisbane flood. Uncertainties about the future impacts of climate change obviate definitive conclusions about future adaptation actions and insights for specific situations cannot be generalised. Economic precepts suggest that governments should limit intervention to cases of genuine market failure, such as the provision of information on likely impacts of climate change including at the local level, or to support for people affected by uninsurable events. But any role as ‘insurer of last resort’ needs to be circumscribed by rigorous social cost-benefit analysis to ensure that government intervention is beneficial, in the context of the need to adapt to climatic changes. Although the phenomenon of ‘government failure’ is generally ignored in the adaptation literature (and often by policy makers), it too can stymie efficient adaptation. A standard justification for government intervention is market failure, including misperception of risk by individuals and businesses. We use Brisbane property prices before and after the January 2011 flood, as well as property-level flood risk information to test the hypothesis that buyers do not accurately perceive the risk of riverine flooding. The results indicate that buyers do take risk into account, and even discriminate between zones of differing flood risk. The concepts of ‘government as insurer of last resort’ and ‘government as insurer of first resort’ as alternative forms of intervention in markets are examined with a view to disambiguation. In contrast to much current thinking in academic and government circles, we conclude that the government should not act as an ‘adaptor of first or last resort’. Rather, government can best contribute to efficient adaptation by reducing the economic costs and institutional barriers to adaptation faced by individuals and organisations. Comprehensive micro-economic reform, and the promotion of institutional flexibility are potential ‘no regrets’ strategies because they will also promote economic growth and welfare. Please cite as: Dobes, L, Jotzo, F, Doupe, P 2013 Adaptor of last resort? An economic perspective on the Government’s role in adaptation to climate change, National Climate Change Adaptation Research Facility, Gold Coast, pp. 81." @default.
- W2140061355 created "2016-06-24" @default.
- W2140061355 creator A5031432093 @default.
- W2140061355 creator A5031555921 @default.
- W2140061355 creator A5074676770 @default.
- W2140061355 date "2013-05-23" @default.
- W2140061355 modified "2023-09-26" @default.
- W2140061355 title "Adaptor of last resort? An economic perspective on the government’s role in adaptation to climate change" @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1491069747 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1494437599 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1526948846 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1544464666 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1548156315 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1550970388 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1552443891 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1552804587 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1554329648 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1556043555 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1586000424 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1588209284 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1839569743 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1859712584 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1968050863 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1975364314 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1982032281 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1983578381 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1985820303 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W1992424812 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2000774715 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2003004462 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2006647242 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2007782080 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2007880057 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2015930340 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2021862747 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2028110729 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2034305567 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2044946463 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2045782423 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2045906015 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2054838761 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2058863401 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2067441684 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2068662554 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2071197323 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2072585631 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2077016814 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2077507714 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2081807099 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2082399164 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2086076529 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2096297092 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2096452841 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2105002885 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2118927154 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2118997265 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2120012334 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2126416729 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2133469585 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2144289297 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2144853855 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2145107370 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2150869534 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2152439681 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2161217898 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2165685322 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2170199526 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2182657471 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2228795405 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2318476657 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2319627574 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2590088954 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2617606220 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2752099845 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2800741211 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W3044646092 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W3122982033 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W3124589520 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W3125757204 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W3210296785 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W41035074 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W653019861 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W6603106 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W889749460 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W947212229 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W99252672 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W2798890068 @default.
- W2140061355 cites W3124287464 @default.
- W2140061355 hasPublicationYear "2013" @default.
- W2140061355 type Work @default.
- W2140061355 sameAs 2140061355 @default.
- W2140061355 citedByCount "3" @default.
- W2140061355 countsByYear W21400613552014 @default.
- W2140061355 countsByYear W21400613552015 @default.
- W2140061355 crossrefType "journal-article" @default.
- W2140061355 hasAuthorship W2140061355A5031432093 @default.
- W2140061355 hasAuthorship W2140061355A5031555921 @default.
- W2140061355 hasAuthorship W2140061355A5074676770 @default.
- W2140061355 hasConcept C100001284 @default.
- W2140061355 hasConcept C10138342 @default.