Matches in SemOpenAlex for { <https://semopenalex.org/work/W2185960642> ?p ?o ?g. }
- W2185960642 abstract "Excerpt] A central problem for those interested in studying and explaining the actions of organizations is how to conceptualize these social phenomena. In particular, because organizations are constituted by individuals, each of whom may seek to achieve his or her interests through the organization, questions of how decisions are made in organizations and whose preferences drive those decisions are critical to explaining organizational actions. Although early organizational scholars spent much time wrestling with these questions (e.g. Barnard 1938; Simon 1947; Parsons 1956; March and Simon 1958), more recent work in organizational studies has tended to elide them, adopting an implicit view of organizations as unitary actors, much like individuals, and in particular, like individuals who operate with a coherent utility function that they seek to maximize (e.g. Porter 1985; Baum et al. 2005; Casciaro and Piskorski 2005; Mezias and Boyle 2005; Jensen 2006). Thus, organizational behavior is seen as reflecting efforts to achieve a specific goal, which is, presumably, that of enhancing the organizations interests. While this may be the dominant conceptualization underlying much contemporary research, other work sharply questions the validity and usefulness of this approach to organizational analysis (March and Simon 1958; Cohen, March, and Olsen 1972; Jackall 1988). Studies in this tradition suggest that it is more appropriate in most instances to conceive of organizations as battlefields, constituted by shifting factions with differing interests that vie for control of the organization; hence, organizational actions should be viewed as reflecting the preferences of a victorious coalition at a given point in time. We suspect that, although most people’s experience in organizations may make them sympathetic to the coalitional view and skeptical of the unitary actor view, the continuing predilection for the latter stems at least in part from problems of deriving systematic predictions of organizational behavior from a more chaotic, coalitional kaleidoscope perspective. A different model of organizations is represented in the work of Robert Michels (1876-1936), who, nearly a century ago, offered his now-famous, pithy summary of the fundamental nature of organizations ([1911] 1962: 365): ‘Who says organization, says oligarchy.’ Drawing on his own experiences with early twentiethcentury German political party organizations, Michels presented the drift to oligarchy as an ‘iron law’, inevitably resulting in the division of even the most expressly democratic organizations into two parts: a small stable set of elites and all the other members. His analysis offered a catalog of the processes and forces that produced such a division, and he postulated that the directives of the elite, while nominally reflecting the set of interests shared by all members, in actuality are driven by their own personal interests in the organization. His provocative (and very pessimistic) arguments have served as the basis for many studies over the years, particularly of organizations specifically formed to represent the interests of groups seeking to promote change in political arenas. Much of this work has been focused on assessing the purported inevitability of the emergence of oligarchies and defining the conditions of the iron law—i.e. those that affect the realization (or suppression) of oligarchic tendencies. In this chapter, we argue that Michels’s core arguments about the nature of oligarchies in organizations, and research generated in response to his work, are not only relevant to understanding the dynamics of political organizations but can be extended as a useful framework for thinking about important aspects of contemporary economic corporations as well. In making this argument, we highlight the parallels between Berle and Means’s analysis (1932) of modern, publicly held corporations and that of Michels. Both analyses address the general organizational problem of ensuring representation of members’ interests. In political organizations, it is the rank-and-file members’ interests that leaders are charged with representing; in publicly held organizations, leaders are primarily responsible for representing the interests of stockholders, as the This article is available at DigitalCommons@ILR: http://digitalcommons.ilr.cornell.edu/articles/1011 nominal owners’ of the firm. In this context, we consider evidence and research on problematic corporate behavior to show how Michels’s work provides a useful framework for understanding these problems and for formulating ways of addressing them." @default.
- W2185960642 created "2016-06-24" @default.
- W2185960642 creator A5027639719 @default.
- W2185960642 creator A5070999528 @default.
- W2185960642 date "2009-01-01" @default.
- W2185960642 modified "2023-09-27" @default.
- W2185960642 title "On Organizations and Oligarchies: Michels in the Twenty-First Century" @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1499966850 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1511601860 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1518244267 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1525327389 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1552853363 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1562992755 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1579515447 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1582968630 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1587877048 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1941781419 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1964242970 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1964995479 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1965952160 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1969532234 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1969973241 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1971285042 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1974338830 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1974928497 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1975716168 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1979927021 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1986540464 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1990073668 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1991795148 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1997008005 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W1999686839 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2003101455 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2010601161 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2011947891 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2015541788 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2019526249 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2021099416 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2022358348 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2023263241 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2026395078 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2030535920 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2036281662 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2036500593 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2038631063 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2045846228 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2046030036 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2048204489 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2048698530 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2057792812 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2061561935 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2064126333 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2067656744 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2070283890 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2074098251 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2077770103 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2077998383 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2085141548 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2100752900 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2114188419 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2116188003 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2119703683 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2148870074 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2148978487 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2151062063 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2151575510 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2153691814 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2162448899 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2168930496 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2197518983 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2295656366 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2313915323 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2314191344 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2318626506 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2323177869 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2328468762 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2328587935 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2328689555 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2331647341 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2334130410 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2480118173 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W2752617332 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W3000133406 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W3021889044 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W3028486165 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W3097618984 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W3121148631 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W3122028926 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W3122340701 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W3122859634 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W3123091116 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W3125062157 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W3125969130 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W3135490280 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W3149395617 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W3177367885 @default.
- W2185960642 cites W582957707 @default.
- W2185960642 hasPublicationYear "2009" @default.
- W2185960642 type Work @default.
- W2185960642 sameAs 2185960642 @default.