Matches in SemOpenAlex for { <https://semopenalex.org/work/W2325165892> ?p ?o ?g. }
- W2325165892 abstract "This paper uses Monte Carlo simulations to evaluate alternative identi cation strategies in VAR estimation of monetary models, and to assess the accuracy of measuring money instability as a cause of output uctuations. I construct theoretical monetary economies using general equilibrium models with cash-in-advance constraints, which also include technology shocks, labor supply shocks, and monetary shocks. Particularly, two economies are characterized: one is fully identi ed and satis es the long-run restriction; another is not fully identi ed and the portion of temporary technology shocks is mixed with demand shocks when applying the long-run restriction. Based on each theoretical model, arti cial economies are then generated through Monte Carlo simulations, which allow me to investigate the reliability of structural VAR estimation under various identifying restrictions. Applying short-run, medium-run, and long-run restrictions on the simulated data, I check for the bias between the average VAR estimates and the true theoretical claim. The ndings show that short-run and medium-run restrictions tend to work better under model uncertainty, particularly because the bias for measuring the e¤ects of monetary shocks using long-run restriction could increase substantially when the underlying economy includes unidenti ed temporary shocks. This experiment supports the claim that monetary shocks contribute no more than one third of the cyclical variance of post-war U.S. output, and suggests that their contribution could in fact be substantially less. Keywords: VAR Estimation, Monetary Shocks, Business Cycle Fluctuations JEL Classi cations: E3, E4, C1, C3 Macro-Financial Linkages Unit, Research Department, International Monetary Fund, 700 19th St. N.W., Washington, DC 20431. Email: bli2@imf.org. Home Page: http://binli.economics.googlepages.com/. I am greatly indebted to Robert E Lucas, Jr., Casey Mulligan, Nancy Stokey, and Harald Uhlig for their support, advice and suggestions. I also thank John Cochrane, Timothy Conley, Christopher Erceg, Paul Evans, Luca Guerrieri, Christopher Gust, Lars Hansen, Erik Hurst, Anil Kashyap, Patrick Kehoe, Frederic Mishkin, Rob Vigfusson, and seminar participants of Money and Banking Workshop, Capital Theory Workshop, and Econometrics Workshop at the University of Chicago, Federal Reserve Board, Ohio State University, Southern Methodist University, SUNY Bu o, Temple University, UIUC, and IMF for helpful comments. All errors are my own. The views expressed in this paper are those of authors and do not necessarily represent those of the IMF. 1 Introduction Structural vector autoregressions (SVARs) are widely used by economists to study sources of business cycle uctuations. Ideally, if the actual economy follows a well-speci ed theoretical model that identi es monetary, preference, and technology shocks, and predicts the economys response, we would study the economy simply based on that model. In reality, because we do not have completely successful models of this sort, most evidence for the e¤ects of di¤erent shocks has to come via SVARs. However, the theoretical models, though far from perfect, can then serve as useful lab experiments to check the reliability of structural VARs. In this paper, we use Monte Carlo simulations of reasonably calibrated dynamic general equilibrium models to evaluate SVAR models for estimating contributions of di¤erent shocks to the business cycle uctuations. In particular, I evaluate alternative identi cation strategies in structural VAR estimation of monetary models, and to assess the accuracy of measuring money instability as a cause of output uctuations. 1.1 Motivation Since the seminal work of Kydland and Prescott (1982), followed by Hansen (1985) and many others, the real business cycle (RBC) economists have claimed a central role for technology shocks driving macroeconomic uctuations in industrialized economies. In these studies, macroeconomic uctuations are interpreted as equilibrium responses to exogenous shocks, in an environment with perfect competition and intertemporally optimizing agents, and the role of monetary policy is assumed to be, at most, secondary. In contrast, the traditional Keynesian monetary models assume a more important role of monetary shocks by emphasizing sticky nominal prices and wage settings, and other market frictions. It is not until more recently that the new generation of small-scale monetary business cycle models with a more extensive range of shocks, (see Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans 2005, and Smets and Wouters 2007 among others) demonstrates that monetary policy shocks, as an exogenous source, may contribute only a small fraction of the forecast variance of output at all horizons. Structural VARs have played a fundamental role in advancing research in this area. Many studies, based on SVARs, con rm that in the postwar United States the exogenous technology shocks measured by the conventional Solow residual account for more than half the uctuations. This is consistent with the classic work of Shapiro and Watson (1988), who employed structural" @default.
- W2325165892 created "2016-06-24" @default.
- W2325165892 creator A5029695887 @default.
- W2325165892 date "2008-01-01" @default.
- W2325165892 modified "2023-09-23" @default.
- W2325165892 title "Evaluating structural vector autoregression models in monetary economies" @default.
- W2325165892 cites W1480041752 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W1482241473 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W1531511688 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W1589985602 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W1602041800 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W1722624015 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W1966731843 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W1989366121 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W2015106170 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W2023147465 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W2038674930 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W2048585019 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W2064376073 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W2115310496 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W2128264096 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W2133492060 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W2143357536 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W2143383948 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W2146207816 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W2148287167 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W2189139855 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W3021064582 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W3021579201 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W3121327890 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W3121595883 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W3121837500 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W3121923888 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W3122092606 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W3123970111 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W3124082850 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W3125785968 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W3125972171 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W3125979221 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W3126103630 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W3146166473 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W3202824610 @default.
- W2325165892 cites W2117351568 @default.
- W2325165892 hasPublicationYear "2008" @default.
- W2325165892 type Work @default.
- W2325165892 sameAs 2325165892 @default.
- W2325165892 citedByCount "2" @default.
- W2325165892 countsByYear W23251658922016 @default.
- W2325165892 crossrefType "journal-article" @default.
- W2325165892 hasAuthorship W2325165892A5029695887 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConcept C105795698 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConcept C121955636 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConcept C126285488 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConcept C133029050 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConcept C139719470 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConcept C149782125 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConcept C162324750 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConcept C187736073 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConcept C19499675 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConcept C196083921 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConcept C204208750 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConcept C33923547 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConcept C556758197 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConcept C83873408 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConcept C96250715 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConceptScore W2325165892C105795698 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConceptScore W2325165892C121955636 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConceptScore W2325165892C126285488 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConceptScore W2325165892C133029050 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConceptScore W2325165892C139719470 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConceptScore W2325165892C149782125 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConceptScore W2325165892C162324750 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConceptScore W2325165892C187736073 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConceptScore W2325165892C19499675 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConceptScore W2325165892C196083921 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConceptScore W2325165892C204208750 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConceptScore W2325165892C33923547 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConceptScore W2325165892C556758197 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConceptScore W2325165892C83873408 @default.
- W2325165892 hasConceptScore W2325165892C96250715 @default.
- W2325165892 hasLocation W23251658921 @default.
- W2325165892 hasOpenAccess W2325165892 @default.
- W2325165892 hasPrimaryLocation W23251658921 @default.
- W2325165892 hasRelatedWork W1539471899 @default.
- W2325165892 hasRelatedWork W2086037098 @default.
- W2325165892 hasRelatedWork W2102001435 @default.
- W2325165892 hasRelatedWork W2117848702 @default.
- W2325165892 hasRelatedWork W2183348619 @default.
- W2325165892 hasRelatedWork W2731325520 @default.
- W2325165892 hasRelatedWork W2793285908 @default.
- W2325165892 hasRelatedWork W2954485346 @default.
- W2325165892 hasRelatedWork W3049531939 @default.
- W2325165892 hasRelatedWork W3091065698 @default.
- W2325165892 hasRelatedWork W3113223205 @default.
- W2325165892 hasRelatedWork W3121184390 @default.
- W2325165892 hasRelatedWork W3121838272 @default.
- W2325165892 hasRelatedWork W3122322413 @default.
- W2325165892 hasRelatedWork W3123970111 @default.
- W2325165892 hasRelatedWork W3124635559 @default.
- W2325165892 hasRelatedWork W3124693077 @default.