Matches in SemOpenAlex for { <https://semopenalex.org/work/W240287347> ?p ?o ?g. }
Showing items 1 to 79 of
79
with 100 items per page.
- W240287347 startingPage "87" @default.
- W240287347 abstract "ABSTRACT This article examines the introduction of flat tax and key Eastern European markets since mid 1990s. It also examines the economic theory of flat tax and analyzes the performance of these revenue instruments in the context of economic performance in transition economies. INTRODUCTION In 1992, Estonian Prime Minister Mart Laar came to power behind a strict policy of liberalization of the economy and an adherence to the principles of neoliberalism. Laar's first order of business was to figure out a way to solve Estonia's miserable tax revenue and collection problems (Smith, 2002). He answered by eliminating Estonia's gradual, or progressive, taxation structure in favor of a 26 percent flat rate on incomes and business. Within 10 years, Estonia gained admission into the European Union and has become a showcase country for why flat tax policies spur economic growth, attract foreign investment, and better collect revenue for governments. With Poland switching from a gradual taxation scheme to a flat tax policy by 2008, 10 countries in Eastern Europe have adopted flat taxes in the last eleven years. other eight countries to adopt are Georgia, Romania, Russia, Serbia, Slovakia, Ukraine, Latvia, and Lithuania. This development is all the more surprising because only one country in the world--Hong Kong--had a flat tax prior to Estonia. Ten years ago, everyone thought the Estonian Prime Minister had gone totally crazy in proposing a flat rate of income said Laar. The idea, which was then considered radical and unrealistic, is now becoming part of mainstream thinking in Central and Eastern Europe. (Laar, 2003). This essay will analyze the reasons behind the adoption of the flat tax. In short, the adoption of the flat tax can in part be contributed to the role of economic in politics and economics. What economic are, and bow they shape policy, will be discussed in the first section of this paper. In the latter section I will more closely examine Eastern Europe and the flat tax, with particular attention paid to the cases of Estonia, Slovakia, Poland, and Hungary. This essay is not intended as a defense of the flat tax, nor implies a call for all countries to adopt the flat tax. This essay is also not a completed project, but the beginning of a larger, more detailed study about the relationship between economic ideas and the adoption of particular policies. cases analyzed represent a 'first cut' with future research left to be done in this area. PART I. ECONOMIC IDEAS AND THE FLAT TAX Policy Explanations: Power, Rationality and Ideas There are three ways the political economy literature might make sense of why states in Eastern Europe adopted flat tax policies. First, power-based explanations would argue that flat tax policies were adopted because certain agents of power coerced states into adopting a policy. A common explanation with Eastern Europe is that external aid agencies like the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund, and Western governments like the United States, forced Eastern European governments to adopt certain policy choices (Vreeland, 2003; Stone, 2001). In this case, political and economic power--or brute coercion--plays a critical role in shaping economic policy. agency of relevant politicians is given little thought because local and even national elites play almost no role according to these theorists. At the extreme, these scholars are reminiscent of Marxists with respect to economics. Because capitalists are in a constant search for new markets, they will do whatever possible to open up once closed countries. Therefore, if the flat tax is seen as a way to do this they will coerce national politicians to achieve their ends. A second explanation, and the conventional wisdom about why Eastern Europe adopted flat tax policies, usually has taken on a functional, or rationalist, logic. It is important to note that both power-coercion explanations and functional explanations are both rational. …" @default.
- W240287347 created "2016-06-24" @default.
- W240287347 creator A5038977512 @default.
- W240287347 date "2008-01-01" @default.
- W240287347 modified "2023-09-27" @default.
- W240287347 title "The Adoption of the Flat Tax: Economic Ideas in Eastern Europe" @default.
- W240287347 hasPublicationYear "2008" @default.
- W240287347 type Work @default.
- W240287347 sameAs 240287347 @default.
- W240287347 citedByCount "1" @default.
- W240287347 crossrefType "journal-article" @default.
- W240287347 hasAuthorship W240287347A5038977512 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C100001284 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C10138342 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C105639569 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C111326686 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C121964417 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C136264566 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C138885662 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C162324750 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C166957645 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C195487862 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C205649164 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C2776092919 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C2776805697 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C2779343474 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C2910001868 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C34447519 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C41895202 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C551662922 @default.
- W240287347 hasConcept C58823610 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C100001284 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C10138342 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C105639569 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C111326686 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C121964417 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C136264566 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C138885662 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C162324750 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C166957645 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C195487862 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C205649164 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C2776092919 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C2776805697 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C2779343474 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C2910001868 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C34447519 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C41895202 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C551662922 @default.
- W240287347 hasConceptScore W240287347C58823610 @default.
- W240287347 hasLocation W2402873471 @default.
- W240287347 hasOpenAccess W240287347 @default.
- W240287347 hasPrimaryLocation W2402873471 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W1534606193 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W1607728942 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W167705813 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W1882852145 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W1982108682 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W2017571749 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W2051834662 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W2332575102 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W2485789824 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W2500889797 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W2503274707 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W25096155 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W2611270581 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W2950984470 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W299851631 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W3084621155 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W3212121853 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W325209754 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W51295416 @default.
- W240287347 hasRelatedWork W3121929411 @default.
- W240287347 hasVolume "17" @default.
- W240287347 isParatext "false" @default.
- W240287347 isRetracted "false" @default.
- W240287347 magId "240287347" @default.
- W240287347 workType "article" @default.