Matches in SemOpenAlex for { <https://semopenalex.org/work/W282382018> ?p ?o ?g. }
Showing items 1 to 76 of
76
with 100 items per page.
- W282382018 endingPage "11" @default.
- W282382018 startingPage "8" @default.
- W282382018 abstract "In 1982, only one out of four employees of U.S. multinationals was located offshore, and over 90 percent of those employees were in industrial countries. By 2007, the share of offshore employment had reached 44 percent, and the majority of those jobs were in low-income countries. These trends in offshoring are mirrored in the statistics on international trade: over the past two decades imports from low-wage countries have more than doubled. (1) Over this same time period, U.S. employment in the manufacturing sector fell sharply and income inequality increased. The downward trend in U.S. manufacturing employment began with the multinationals and coincided with their expansion offshore: between 1982 and 1999 U.S. based multinationals reduced employment domestically by 4 million workers. Our research is motivated by these parallel developments and seeks to understand the implications for American workers. Are U.S. Based Multinationals Exporting Jobs? This question has always been of interest to policymakers and is arguably more important now than ever before. Accordingly, there is no shortage of academic research on this topic. (2) The problem is that the answer to the question seems to change depending on the study. Brainard and Riker (3) find that labor employed by overseas affiliates substitutes at the margin for labor employed by parents at home, but they emphasize that the results differ depending on geographic location. In particular, they emphasize strong substitution between workers in developing countries, such as between workers in countries like Mexico and China. More recently, Desai, Foley, and Hines (4) have shown that increases in employment abroad are positively correlated with employment at home. They interpret this as evidence that expansion abroad by U.S. based multinationals leads to job creation at home. [FIGURE 1 OMITTED] Our research examines this seemingly contradictory evidence in an attempt to bring closure to this debate. We begin by establishing that the relationship between multinational employment at home and abroad changes depending on the location of U.S. multinational activity. (5) We show that for affiliates in high-income countries, there is a positive correlation between employment at home and abroad, suggesting that foreign employment of U.S. multinationals may be complementary to domestic employment (Figure 1). However, we also establish that this positive correlation between employment in the United States and employment in high income locations is driven by a contraction in employment in both locations, not by employment growth. [FIGURE 2 OMITTED] For firms that operate in developing countries, however, employment contractions in the United States are matched by affiliate employment growth in low income locations. As shown in Figure 2, workers in low-income countries appear to be substitutes for U.S. workers in several highly visible industries, including computers, electronics, and transportation. We can explain these apparently conflicting results by distinguishing between the different motives for foreign investment. (6) Markusen and Maskus (7) show how different incentives for foreign investment lead to different organizational structures, which should produce different degrees of substitution between employment at home and abroad. Horizontal multinationals (H-FDI), defined as firms that produce the same products in different locations, are primarily motivated to locate abroad by costs. For H-FDI, investment abroad substitutes for parent exports, and foreign-affiliate employment should substitute for home employment. Vertically integrated enterprises (V-FDI) are motivated to locate different components of production in different locations by factor price differences. For V-FDI, sourcing different stages of production elsewhere can be complementary to employment growth at home. Another theoretical framework that emphasizes trade in has been developed by Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg: they show that falling costs of offshoring specific tasks can be associated with higher wages at home. …" @default.
- W282382018 created "2016-06-24" @default.
- W282382018 creator A5015883568 @default.
- W282382018 creator A5029405627 @default.
- W282382018 date "2011-12-22" @default.
- W282382018 modified "2023-09-24" @default.
- W282382018 title "Offshoring, international trade, and American workers" @default.
- W282382018 cites W1577375906 @default.
- W282382018 cites W1999800658 @default.
- W282382018 cites W2002007234 @default.
- W282382018 cites W2151271248 @default.
- W282382018 cites W2152431833 @default.
- W282382018 cites W2891509446 @default.
- W282382018 cites W3023628643 @default.
- W282382018 cites W3122074400 @default.
- W282382018 cites W3122398734 @default.
- W282382018 cites W3122700437 @default.
- W282382018 cites W3124603990 @default.
- W282382018 hasPublicationYear "2011" @default.
- W282382018 type Work @default.
- W282382018 sameAs 282382018 @default.
- W282382018 citedByCount "0" @default.
- W282382018 crossrefType "journal-article" @default.
- W282382018 hasAuthorship W282382018A5015883568 @default.
- W282382018 hasAuthorship W282382018A5029405627 @default.
- W282382018 hasConcept C144133560 @default.
- W282382018 hasConcept C145236788 @default.
- W282382018 hasConcept C162324750 @default.
- W282382018 hasConcept C162853370 @default.
- W282382018 hasConcept C2777388388 @default.
- W282382018 hasConcept C39302471 @default.
- W282382018 hasConcept C4249254 @default.
- W282382018 hasConcept C46934059 @default.
- W282382018 hasConcept C50522688 @default.
- W282382018 hasConcept C83864248 @default.
- W282382018 hasConceptScore W282382018C144133560 @default.
- W282382018 hasConceptScore W282382018C145236788 @default.
- W282382018 hasConceptScore W282382018C162324750 @default.
- W282382018 hasConceptScore W282382018C162853370 @default.
- W282382018 hasConceptScore W282382018C2777388388 @default.
- W282382018 hasConceptScore W282382018C39302471 @default.
- W282382018 hasConceptScore W282382018C4249254 @default.
- W282382018 hasConceptScore W282382018C46934059 @default.
- W282382018 hasConceptScore W282382018C50522688 @default.
- W282382018 hasConceptScore W282382018C83864248 @default.
- W282382018 hasIssue "4" @default.
- W282382018 hasLocation W2823820181 @default.
- W282382018 hasOpenAccess W282382018 @default.
- W282382018 hasPrimaryLocation W2823820181 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W1556893497 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W1600368546 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W1964222626 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W2125729456 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W2236642661 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W2540118301 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W2890286274 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W3121422204 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W3121945277 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W3122158152 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W3123337701 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W3124568965 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W3125253681 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W3145450149 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W317331529 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W3195731397 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W4541540 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W93530414 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W2465641880 @default.
- W282382018 hasRelatedWork W3121409440 @default.
- W282382018 hasVolume "2011" @default.
- W282382018 isParatext "false" @default.
- W282382018 isRetracted "false" @default.
- W282382018 magId "282382018" @default.
- W282382018 workType "article" @default.