Matches in SemOpenAlex for { <https://semopenalex.org/work/W3122321222> ?p ?o ?g. }
Showing items 1 to 67 of
67
with 100 items per page.
- W3122321222 startingPage "6" @default.
- W3122321222 abstract "I. INTRODUCTION In the international taxation literature, one cannot so much as scan an opening paragraph without substantial danger of learning once again that we live in an age of globalization, worldwide capital mobility, increasing inter-dependency, and (with suitable drumroll) threats to national sovereignty. Tedium aside, however, these claims have the virtue, at least-except for the last of them-of being unmistakably true. Why isn't national sovereignty endangered (or at least not unmistakably so) by global economic integration? If one defines it as national autarky, then presumably it is endangered-if only because, as the people of North Korea and Myanmar might attest, the global trends make autarky ever more unappealing. Suppose, however, that one instead defines sovereignty in a conventional international law sense, as embracing political independence, territorial integrity, exclusive jurisdiction over one's territory and residents, and freedom from intervention by foreign sovereigns.' Then the fact that countries have ever more extensive strategic interactions and ability to affect each other is not a violation of sovereignty; rather, it is part of the context in which they exercise sovereignty. Even if countries have less latitude to make policy in disregard of outside competitive pressures or emerging worldwide uniformities, this might be viewed as merely influencing how they may choose to exercise their sovereignty. Still, a debate about global economic trends in relation to sovereignty is too semantic to hold much ultimate interest. A more rewarding topic is how the trends affect countries' strategic interactions. Harmonization and competition are two wellknown modes of interaction between countries' legal systems, sometimes viewed as IMAGE FORMULA6polar opposites, but often overlapping. For example, a race to the bottom may involve effective harmonization through competition. In evaluating the consequences of countries' strategic interactions, two key norms to keep in mind are national welfare and worldwide welfare. When the two norms offer consistent counsel, countries may find it easy to achieve mutual gain through cooperation. Even when the two norms seem to conflict, they can, in theory, be reconciled through policies that aim at maximizing worldwide welfare, but offer compensation to the losers. However, this Coase Theorem truism is subject to the usual problem of transaction costs, such as those with the underlying prisoner's dilemmas, where cooperation is best for the group but not for anyone acting in isolation. National and worldwide welfare also may be pushed apart by bargaining problems in a bilateral monopoly, wherein each actor seeks to capture as much as possible of the surplus that is available through cooperation, even at the risk of destroying it all. International income taxation provides a good illustration of how national and worldwide welfare may interrelate in practice. Countries frequently income on both a and a residence basis, reflecting their power and accepted legal jurisdiction both in personam and in rem. Given these dual claims, if an American invests in France or vice versa, both countries may feel entitled to the same income at their full statutory rates. However, such a double tax may lead to inefficient deterrence of cross-border investment, to the detriment of the government and people of both countries. Coordination of the two countries' claims may help mitigate this result. Countries around the world have therefore agreed, through a web of bilateral treaties, to coordinate their competing claims via source country priority. Many countries, including the United States, do this by offering foreign credits that effectively rebate the on what they deem to be foreign income, to the extent not in excess of the domestic on such income.2 Implicit in the allowance of foreign credits is the view that other countries' taxes on the outbound investments of one's residents are relevant to one's own policy choice regarding taxation of these investments. …" @default.
- W3122321222 created "2021-02-01" @default.
- W3122321222 creator A5088387931 @default.
- W3122321222 date "2002-10-01" @default.
- W3122321222 modified "2023-09-26" @default.
- W3122321222 title "Money on the Table?: Responding to Cross-Border Tax Arbitrage" @default.
- W3122321222 hasPublicationYear "2002" @default.
- W3122321222 type Work @default.
- W3122321222 sameAs 3122321222 @default.
- W3122321222 citedByCount "2" @default.
- W3122321222 countsByYear W31223212222019 @default.
- W3122321222 crossrefType "journal-article" @default.
- W3122321222 hasAuthorship W3122321222A5088387931 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConcept C100243477 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConcept C138921699 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConcept C155202549 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConcept C162324750 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConcept C17744445 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConcept C186229450 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConcept C190253527 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConcept C199539241 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConcept C2776949292 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConcept C2781301651 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConcept C55447825 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConcept C94625758 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConceptScore W3122321222C100243477 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConceptScore W3122321222C138921699 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConceptScore W3122321222C155202549 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConceptScore W3122321222C162324750 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConceptScore W3122321222C17744445 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConceptScore W3122321222C186229450 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConceptScore W3122321222C190253527 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConceptScore W3122321222C199539241 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConceptScore W3122321222C2776949292 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConceptScore W3122321222C2781301651 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConceptScore W3122321222C55447825 @default.
- W3122321222 hasConceptScore W3122321222C94625758 @default.
- W3122321222 hasIssue "2" @default.
- W3122321222 hasLocation W31223212221 @default.
- W3122321222 hasOpenAccess W3122321222 @default.
- W3122321222 hasPrimaryLocation W31223212221 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W1526583768 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W1545537246 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W1570549476 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W1582724664 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W190223762 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W2270667040 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W2277141000 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W2480148206 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W2607479838 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W2624299606 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W3005830281 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W3082894080 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W3093772912 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W3117463647 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W3122627470 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W3122920826 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W3123420481 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W3176624750 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W66889273 @default.
- W3122321222 hasRelatedWork W171727690 @default.
- W3122321222 hasVolume "3" @default.
- W3122321222 isParatext "false" @default.
- W3122321222 isRetracted "false" @default.
- W3122321222 magId "3122321222" @default.
- W3122321222 workType "article" @default.