Matches in SemOpenAlex for { <https://semopenalex.org/work/W3151490229> ?p ?o ?g. }
Showing items 1 to 76 of
76
with 100 items per page.
- W3151490229 abstract "Property rights are an essential economic institution. As the great UCLA economist Harold Demsetz famously argued, property rights spur specialization, investment, and competition, which in turn increase productivity, innovation, and wealth throughout the economy.The same holds true for intellectual property rights, including patents, which are no less important than their traditional counterparts in facilitating innovation and the efficient organization of productive economic activity, particularly in the modern, high-tech economy. A wealth of literature indicates that much, if not most, of the value of innovation is passed on to consumers in the form of lower prices and higher quality goods and services. Indeed, as Nobel Laureate William Nordhaus finds, even in the presence of patents to facilitate the appropriability of the value of innovation by inventors, “only a miniscule fraction of the social returns from technological advances over the 1948- 2001 period was captured by producers, indicating that most of the benefits of technological change are passed on to consumers rather than captured by producers.” Thus, although measurement problems plague such research, there is strong evidence that nations with greater levels of patent protection have historically achieved significantly higher innovative output than those with lower levels of patent protection.Nevertheless, a significant body of academic and policy work has argued—with very real policy success—that patent rights in the U.S. have been too strong. The past two decades have witnessed a significant weakening of patent protection in the U.S. as courts, legislators, and several private organizations have progressively chipped away at some of the key features of patent protection. This includes the availability of injunctions, the amount of damages awarded to victims of patent infringement, and other, more subtle changes, such as curbs on fee-shifting between parties to patent litigation.Behind many of these changes lies a powerful intellectual movement, alleging that excessive patent protection is holding back western economies. These critics chiefly fear that the owners of the standard essential patents (“SEPs”) crucial to much of modern technology are charging their commercial partners too much for the rights to use their patents—referred to as patent holdup and royalty stacking—and that so-called patent trolls (“patent-assertion entities” or “PAEs”) are deterring innovation by small startups by employing “extortionate” litigation tactics. Oversimplifying, the argument is that, by selecting certain winning technologies, standardization artificially weakens implementers’ bargaining position vis a vis patent holders. Accordingly, critics argue that the royalties charged by SEP holders should not exceed those that they could have obtained before their technology was included in a standard. However, there is little evidence beyond occasional anecdotes to support the first of these concerns, and a growing body of empirical research points in the opposite direction. And the latter concern, while real, is complex, and the optimal policy response should address these complexities more than typical proposals do. Yet despite the limited evidence and complexities, policymakers have been quick to act on them.It may even be the case that the policy changes that have been made are impeding the ability of owners of SEPs to enforce their rights to such an extent that they are now being under-rewarded. Most notably, there is at least some evidence to suggest that the looser enforcement of IP rights is resulting in holdout behavior (i.e., situations where would-be licensees avoid concluding a license agreement because they know that they are shielded from legal repercussions for infringement).While this does not appear to have resulted in a marked decrease in innovative output so far, there is certainly a risk of that happening, especially if lawmakers continue to alter the legal regime in ways that systematically disadvantage patent holders. Indeed, although the causes are unclear, already there are concerns about secular stagnation and the slowdown in productivity growth. In that context, policies that weaken incentives to innovate seem like the height of folly. Moreover, since many important innovations bear fruit only many years after the initial investment in research and development, any subsequent change of course may have few short-term benefits and might even have short-term costs, making it politically difficult if not impossible to change course once more significant adverse effects on innovation start to appear.Against this backdrop, this article uses the analytical framework of law and economics to offer insights into what policies can help reduce unnecessarily burdensome patent litigation and thereby accelerate the pace of technological progress. Among other things, law and economics enables us to better understand the incentive effects of different rules regarding the enforceability of patents and the optimal balance of remedies to produce the greatest social welfare. The article begins by discussing the critical role that patents play in fostering dynamic technology markets (Section I). It then reviews recent legal and policy developments concerning the availability of injunctions (Section II) and the size of damage awards (Section III). It then considers other legal rules and procedures that may affect innovation incentives (Section IV). We conclude by discussing the policy implications of these developments (Section V)." @default.
- W3151490229 created "2021-04-13" @default.
- W3151490229 creator A5016496508 @default.
- W3151490229 creator A5045239080 @default.
- W3151490229 creator A5057676636 @default.
- W3151490229 creator A5087641096 @default.
- W3151490229 date "2020-01-01" @default.
- W3151490229 modified "2023-09-27" @default.
- W3151490229 title "The Deterioration of Appropriate Remedies in Patent Disputes" @default.
- W3151490229 doi "https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3707573" @default.
- W3151490229 hasPublicationYear "2020" @default.
- W3151490229 type Work @default.
- W3151490229 sameAs 3151490229 @default.
- W3151490229 citedByCount "0" @default.
- W3151490229 crossrefType "journal-article" @default.
- W3151490229 hasAuthorship W3151490229A5016496508 @default.
- W3151490229 hasAuthorship W3151490229A5045239080 @default.
- W3151490229 hasAuthorship W3151490229A5057676636 @default.
- W3151490229 hasAuthorship W3151490229A5087641096 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C119857082 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C137996800 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C139719470 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C144133560 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C162324750 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C175444787 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C17744445 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C18903297 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C199539241 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C204983608 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C27548731 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C2776291640 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C34447519 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C34974158 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C41008148 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C50522688 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C86511162 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C86803240 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C91306197 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConcept C94625758 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C119857082 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C137996800 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C139719470 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C144133560 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C162324750 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C175444787 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C17744445 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C18903297 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C199539241 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C204983608 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C27548731 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C2776291640 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C34447519 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C34974158 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C41008148 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C50522688 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C86511162 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C86803240 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C91306197 @default.
- W3151490229 hasConceptScore W3151490229C94625758 @default.
- W3151490229 hasLocation W31514902291 @default.
- W3151490229 hasOpenAccess W3151490229 @default.
- W3151490229 hasPrimaryLocation W31514902291 @default.
- W3151490229 hasRelatedWork W11403409 @default.
- W3151490229 hasRelatedWork W138797 @default.
- W3151490229 hasRelatedWork W19423098 @default.
- W3151490229 hasRelatedWork W19959033 @default.
- W3151490229 hasRelatedWork W29382592 @default.
- W3151490229 hasRelatedWork W5661758 @default.
- W3151490229 hasRelatedWork W6746549 @default.
- W3151490229 hasRelatedWork W7432539 @default.
- W3151490229 hasRelatedWork W8496960 @default.
- W3151490229 hasRelatedWork W9968372 @default.
- W3151490229 isParatext "false" @default.
- W3151490229 isRetracted "false" @default.
- W3151490229 magId "3151490229" @default.
- W3151490229 workType "article" @default.