Matches in SemOpenAlex for { <https://semopenalex.org/work/W68279638> ?p ?o ?g. }
Showing items 1 to 75 of
75
with 100 items per page.
- W68279638 endingPage "285" @default.
- W68279638 startingPage "273" @default.
- W68279638 abstract "For two players with identical preferences, cake-cutting procedures, such as Cut-and-Choose (Brams & Taylor, 1996) and the Surplus Procedure (Brams, Jones, & Klamler, 2006), guarantee that each player receives exactly half of the cake, according to their preferences. In essence, receiving exactly half is a worst-case scenario because when their preferences are not identical, the opportunity often exists for both players to receive more than half of the cake, measured by their preferences. This potential reward is balanced by risk, as these differences in preferences provide an incentive for players to misrepresent their preferences in an effort to gain a more valuable piece. In contrast, players may not be able to exploit information about an opponent's preferences when indivisible objects are allocated to two players, even when the players ' preferences are different. Our purpose is to determine the structure of, relationship between, and frequency of two players' preferences for which players receive their worst or best possible outcomes when dividing a finite set of indivisible goods, independent of strategic behavior. Kohler and Chandrasekaharan (1971) pose and solve three optimization problems in which a finite set of players, with linear preference orders over the items, alternate taking turns selecting a number of items from a set of indivisible items. We adopt their framework, as Brams and Straffin (1979) do, to the case when two players alternate selecting a single item from a set of indivisible items. Although Kohler and Chandrasekaharan (1971) assume that players have values associated with each item and subsets are valued according to the sum of the values of its objects, like Brams and Straffin (1979), we assume that the players ' preferences for subsets of items are partially ordered, induced by the linear orders." @default.
- W68279638 created "2016-06-24" @default.
- W68279638 creator A5036147394 @default.
- W68279638 creator A5045867205 @default.
- W68279638 date "2009-02-09" @default.
- W68279638 modified "2023-09-27" @default.
- W68279638 title "Bruhat Orders and the Sequential Selection of Indivisible Items" @default.
- W68279638 cites W1551177513 @default.
- W68279638 cites W1968141842 @default.
- W68279638 cites W1974972171 @default.
- W68279638 cites W2025974292 @default.
- W68279638 cites W2036247328 @default.
- W68279638 cites W4236082126 @default.
- W68279638 cites W4237930722 @default.
- W68279638 cites W4240141524 @default.
- W68279638 doi "https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-79128-7_15" @default.
- W68279638 hasPublicationYear "2009" @default.
- W68279638 type Work @default.
- W68279638 sameAs 68279638 @default.
- W68279638 citedByCount "4" @default.
- W68279638 countsByYear W682796382012 @default.
- W68279638 countsByYear W682796382015 @default.
- W68279638 countsByYear W682796382019 @default.
- W68279638 crossrefType "book-chapter" @default.
- W68279638 hasAuthorship W68279638A5036147394 @default.
- W68279638 hasAuthorship W68279638A5045867205 @default.
- W68279638 hasConcept C134306372 @default.
- W68279638 hasConcept C144237770 @default.
- W68279638 hasConcept C154945302 @default.
- W68279638 hasConcept C162324750 @default.
- W68279638 hasConcept C162392398 @default.
- W68279638 hasConcept C165696696 @default.
- W68279638 hasConcept C175444787 @default.
- W68279638 hasConcept C177264268 @default.
- W68279638 hasConcept C199360897 @default.
- W68279638 hasConcept C2781249084 @default.
- W68279638 hasConcept C29122968 @default.
- W68279638 hasConcept C33923547 @default.
- W68279638 hasConcept C38652104 @default.
- W68279638 hasConcept C41008148 @default.
- W68279638 hasConcept C81917197 @default.
- W68279638 hasConceptScore W68279638C134306372 @default.
- W68279638 hasConceptScore W68279638C144237770 @default.
- W68279638 hasConceptScore W68279638C154945302 @default.
- W68279638 hasConceptScore W68279638C162324750 @default.
- W68279638 hasConceptScore W68279638C162392398 @default.
- W68279638 hasConceptScore W68279638C165696696 @default.
- W68279638 hasConceptScore W68279638C175444787 @default.
- W68279638 hasConceptScore W68279638C177264268 @default.
- W68279638 hasConceptScore W68279638C199360897 @default.
- W68279638 hasConceptScore W68279638C2781249084 @default.
- W68279638 hasConceptScore W68279638C29122968 @default.
- W68279638 hasConceptScore W68279638C33923547 @default.
- W68279638 hasConceptScore W68279638C38652104 @default.
- W68279638 hasConceptScore W68279638C41008148 @default.
- W68279638 hasConceptScore W68279638C81917197 @default.
- W68279638 hasLocation W682796381 @default.
- W68279638 hasOpenAccess W68279638 @default.
- W68279638 hasPrimaryLocation W682796381 @default.
- W68279638 hasRelatedWork W1568958474 @default.
- W68279638 hasRelatedWork W1849288175 @default.
- W68279638 hasRelatedWork W1880294444 @default.
- W68279638 hasRelatedWork W1981838936 @default.
- W68279638 hasRelatedWork W2031468198 @default.
- W68279638 hasRelatedWork W2061112603 @default.
- W68279638 hasRelatedWork W2063821932 @default.
- W68279638 hasRelatedWork W3121667745 @default.
- W68279638 hasRelatedWork W3148160091 @default.
- W68279638 hasRelatedWork W4229083696 @default.
- W68279638 isParatext "false" @default.
- W68279638 isRetracted "false" @default.
- W68279638 magId "68279638" @default.
- W68279638 workType "book-chapter" @default.